Differences

This shows you the differences between two versions of the page.

Link to this comparison view

Both sides previous revision Previous revision
Next revision
Previous revision
effects_of_divorce_on_u.s._economic_growth [2016/01/07 21:26]
marri
effects_of_divorce_on_u.s._economic_growth [2022/03/23 16:14] (current)
Line 1: Line 1:
 +==========Effects of Divorce on U.S. Economic Growth==========
 +
 +[[effects_of_marriage_on_financial_stability|Marriage]] is a causal agent of economic growth. It constitutes one-third to one-fourth((There are many reasons for the reporting uncertainty here, e.g. the wage stagnation that occurred in the 1970s (Chart 6) and also the lower growth in wages for workers later in their working life, a well-understood human capital effect—see [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/decline-of-economic-growth-human-capital-and-population-change/]] and Becker, //Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education//, see n. 7. What is not //uncertain// in this reporting is the increase in the productivity from marriage. Its effect is stable across the wage stagnation of the 1970s, cf. Charts 4 and 6. That is, it is //robust across macro-economic evolutions over the decades//. Also, as we employ census 1% samples, there is little statistical/ systematic uncertainty in the deduced parameters. (E.g. the //t// values testing the equality of what are usually notoriously badly diffused [difference-in-difference] statistics—the different income growths [of Charts 4 and 6]—are over 10, with essentially infinite sample sizes].) This fact is used in the development to follow by speaking of the parameters as if they are statistically certain.)) of the human capital contribution of household heads to macro-economic growth (Chart 1).((George Akerlof, “Men Without Children,” //The Economic Journal// 108 (March 1998): 287-309.)) ((The total contribution of human capital to growth of domestic product in turn is large, being of equal proportion to the other two contributing factors: size of the labor pool and physical capital (see again Chart 1). See [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/decline-of-economic-growth-human-capital-and-population-change/]] and references therein for proofs of these statements.)) [[effects.of.divorce.on.financial.stability|Divorce]] removes this agent of economic growth. 
 +
 +{{ :chart_1.png?direct&550 |Macro-Economic Growth Components}}
 +
 +=====1. Effects of Divorce on Productivity=====
 +
 +A revolution occurred in marital practice in the United States (see Chart 2). Over the course of the 1960s and 1970s, the fraction of marriages that would eventually dissolve tripled for 30-year-olds and quadrupled for 40- and 50-year-olds. The rate of divorce has remained roughly constant since then, though marriage has become less frequent.((Later marital years are marked by increased marital stability—see Sally Clarke, //Advance Report of Final Divorce Statistics, 1989 and 1990//, vol. 43, supplemental, techreport (CDC, 1995), and Chart 2 itself. The baby-boom, in which a population concentration exists, have entered their later marital years. The raw (total population) divorce rates promulgated by the media have nominally declined as this population concentration moves into these years of increasing marital stability.))
 +
 +{{ :chart_2.png?direct&550 |Percent of First Marriages that will Dissolve over the Decades}}
 +
 +The effects of the increased divorced rates are shown in Chart 3 below. The population of single men (bottom, orange area) is approximately proportional to population size, as marriage rates had not yet plummeted during the graphed period. The intact married population of men (center, blue area) increasingly transitions into the divorced population of men (top, red area) as time goes on and the divorce revolution affects the U.S. population. Holding divorces to their 1950s transition rates (Chart 2) allows researchers to differentiate two populations: those men who would (still) be divorced under the old regime (red area above the black line) and those who experience divorce under the new regime (red area below the black line).((Chart 3 is an idealization of population components’ change given by a model. Chart 4 is age-group focused. This depiction captures part of the age-group effect on chart 2.)) 
 +
 +{{ :chart_3.png?direct&550 |Depiction of Divorce Flowing through the Adult U.S. Population}}
 +
 +Chart 4 shows the causal effect of divorce for those men who experienced divorce because of the divorce revolution. For this group of “new” divorcés, the rate of income increase, a measure of productivity growth,((This is true because labor markets clear. It is always in the firms’ interest to increase wages until the value of the extra bit of work gained by those wages—as contributed to production—balances with that additional wage cost. See Robert Barro and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, //Economic Growth//, Second Edition (Cambridge: MIT Press, 2003). See [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/the-divorce-revolution-perpetually-reduces-u-s-economic-growth/]] for the full argument. Also see Footnote 14.)) changes. Their [[effects_of_marriage_on_workforce_participation|rate of productivity growth decreases]] to nearly half that of single, never-married men.((The relative rates of productivity growth shown in Chart 4 continue to hold when we investigate this effect within education classes.)) ((The rates reported are mean rates of change (top-coded) income distributions. Top-coding conveniently eliminates distortions of (a very small number of) high earners’ earnings. These earnings would otherwise measure less human capital and more social capital and risk calculi determining those earners’ wages. The income distribution of divorced and also of single men are always stochastically dominated by the distribution of income for married men. This, these means correctly characterize comparisons of the whole distributions. Furthermore, exploration of these distributions shows the results of these findings to hold for different quintile classes of these populations.)) Since divorce was relatively uncommon in the 1950s, and because around half of marriages end in divorce now (Chart 2),((To test this, simply multiple the probabilities of marriage survival across the ages given by Chart 2.)) ((The reason the red Divorced population does not overtake half the blue Married population in Chart 3 is because there is a (large) mass of older, more stable marriages already extant in the evolving U.S. population; the divorce revolution numerically works less on these marriages. Also, it takes time for the divorces of Chart 2 to affect newly entered marriages. These facts induce what is known as a lag-effect in the population dynamics, a phenomenon always present in such dynamical systems, and sometimes termed population momentum in the field of demographics.)) ((This assertion can be doubly substantiated by the happy fact that the Census 2010 American Community Survey again has the necessary statistics on divorce to compute the completed marriage fractions for 60-year-olds, i.e. for those men who were 20 years if age once the divorce revolution was enculturated (by 1970). For these 60-year-olds, 50%±2% of marriages remain intact, and for 50-year-olds 55%±3% of marriages remain intact. Chart 2 helps show that 50-year-olds are on track to repeat the 60-year-olds’ performance.)) it can be said that it is this “average man” whose productivity is causally affected by the divorce revolution.((One must interpret “average” in this “local population group affected by the transition to divorce” sense.))
 +
 +{{ :chart_4.png?direct&550 |Comparison of Productivity Gains for Single, Married, & Ever-Divorced Heads of Household Across their 30s}}
 +
 +=====2. Link Between Divorce and Income=====
 +
 +As workers move from the married state to the divorced state they bring their productivity in the marketplace with them. It is clear that this productivity changes because there is a change in their income,((This analysis uses wage income so that it can measure human capital. A pseudo-wage also exists in defined benefits plans, which we cannot measure from census long forms. The neglect of this pseudo-wage results in an underestimate of marriage productivity differentials, likely by a simple factor deducible from the differential (annualized) annuity contribution rates as a fraction of total compensation. This assumes firms act in good faith and actually expect to pay said annuity.)) which is the value the market is putting on that potentially changed productivity.((That married men do not simply receive special treatment follows from general GDP [that is, production] considerations: See the end of Footnote 21; workers, by the analysis of [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/decline-of-economic-growth-human-capital-and-population-change/]], are remunerated consistently for their labor + human capital contribution to production. However, in the 1960s [and the 1970s, through there are complicating factors], this remuneration would have been too high a fraction of growth if we did not in addition take into account the wage-rate [and human capital-accrual, //a posteriori//] decrease occurring in the population of newly minted divorcés of that period. See the last paragraph of Footnote 21. To reiterate, after translating the observed decrease in wage increases of these new divorcés, into its component of GDP---that group’s contribution to Product---we recover the excellent [growth accounting] correspondence between human capital + population + physical capital growth and overall GDP growth exhibited in Charts 1 and 2 of [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/decline-of-economic-growth-human-capital-and-population-change/]], now over a 70 year post-war period.
 +\\ To summarize that development, we anchor individual productivity in overall (domestic) productivity and show wages correspond to that individual productivity. Now we do it for a considerably longer period of time.)) 
 +
 +The divorce revolution has a perpetual effect on the productivity of heads of (broken) households (Chart 4). Henry Potrykus of the Marriage and Religion Research Institute developed a model based on a natural experiment to determine both the transitions of workers from singlehood, through marriage, and into now-common divorce, as well as the productivity effects (if any) of these transitions. This model quantitatively describes population flows between the sub-populations of single, intact married, and ever-divorced men that occurred between the decennial census. The model also tracks the incomes of these men, properly accounting for incomes ported between sub-populations as these men transition to different sub-populations. That is, these men “brought their incomes with them” as they transitioned between states in life. In this way we are able to accurately depict the income dynamics of these groups, as marriage and divorce affect them.
 +
 +Chart 5 shows [[effects_of_marriage_on_workforce_participation|married men earn substantially more]] than single men, and more than divorced men. Some researchers hypothesize that this is due to a “selection effect”: Women may select higher earners as mates, although women may equally select more exciting and risk-prone men. Similarly, men who innately have higher human capital may be more marriage-prone, although high human capital men may equally well choose exciting, risky women. This seems to be statistically a closed problem for the U.S.((Meta-regression still shows some marriage premium for U.S. males, while for other populations the selection effect plus the effect investigated in this paper---increased productivity growth for married men---essentially zeroes out any potential (instantaneous) marriage premium. It should be noted that different countries have different [enculturated] courting practices. See Megan Leonard and Thomas Stanley, “A Meta-Regression Analysis of the Male Marriage Wage Premium,” in //Meta-Analysis of Economics Research// (2010).))
 +
 +{{ :chart_5.png?direct&550 |Average Income for Single, Married, and Ever-Divorced Males Aged 25-35}}
 +
 +A natural experiment helps explain how marital status affects productivity. As Charts 4 and 6 show, the rate of change in earnings year over year are consistently higher for men in intact marriages than among single or ever-divorced men. It is remarkable that these differences in these rates of change (the distance between the lines in Charts 4 and 6) are more consistently constant than income growth itself: Note how in Chart 6 workers over their 40s and 50s experience wage stagnation (zero income growth) from 1970 to 1980, while the differential productivity of marrieds relative to the other classes of men stays essentially constant.((Though there was economic growth, cf. [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/decline-of-economic-growth-human-capital-and-population-change/]] Chart 2, so the “stagflation” of the 1970s was really a wage stagnation.)) 
 +
 +{{ :chart_6.png?direct&550 |Comparison of Productivity Gains for Single, Married, and Ever-Divorced Heads of Households}}
 +
 +In this experiment, there are two groups of divorced men (depicted in Chart 3): those that would have divorced anyway, and “new” divorcés, a product of the divorce revolution. If these new divorced men were from a “least-productive sub-pool” within the sub-population of married men,((This is either sense of total wage or wage rate-of-change.)) the remaining (smaller group of) married men would exhibit an apparent productivity boost, as this “dross” of new divorced men would finally be removed from that sub-population of marrieds. But there is no change in the distance between the wage-growth curves as the country evolves and the divorce revolution plays out (Chart 4, Chart 3).((Even with the massive wage stagnation of the 1970s---Charts 4 and 6.)) As this boost to the upper curve is not seen in the census data (no change in distance between curves), this "dross” cannot exist.
 +
 +Similarly, if the new divorced men maintained their old productivity growth, a “most productive sub-pool” within the sub-population of divorced men would see a productivity boost. These newly minted divorcés would now be contributing a higher level of productivity to the divorced sub-population’s productivity. Again, there is no change in the distance between the macro-economically relevant wage-growth curves as the country evolves and the divorce revolution plays out. As this boost to the lower curve is not seen in the census data (no change in the distance between curves), this more productive sub-pool cannot exist. Chart 7 summarizes this argument.((The statistically improbable case where only an exactly balancing productivity class of men transfers from the married to divorced state (exactly balancing productivity in the sense  that their productivity is just that much higher than those otherwise divorced to move the lower curve up by the same amount the dross-clearing moves the upper curve up) may be rejected as the curves in Charts 4, 6 move down during this period, both absolutely and more importantly relative to the Single sub-population---an “independent third baseline.” This is further contradicted by the fact that the divorce revolution occurred over two decades. Hence we have two periods wherein divorce affects two different populations. These populations differ generationally, and may be situated in different macro-economic environments. They did enter into marriage at different rates, for different ages. Thus, as the divorce revolution works its way through the population, divorce affects different types of divorced men. That is, if there were exactly balancing productivity “dross” transferred in the 1960s, this unlikely event occurs again in the 1970s with a new, even larger set of just-divorced men. This would mean divorce probability exactly determines human capital growth, i.e. that there is a one-to-one correspondence (across generations, across ages for those generations, and across macro-economic environments), a surprising finding and one that would say marital fidelity decides labor-marketing efficacy.))
 +
 +{{ :chart_7.png?direct&550 |New Divorcées' Productivity Affecting Populations' Productivity Growth: Only Through Personal Loss to Growth}}
 +
 +Pre-divorce, divorced men are not less productive than other married men. Post-divorce, these new divorcés are not more productive than those whose class they are entering. //Divorced men become less productive through divorce// (Chart 8 and 9).((Furthermore, this reduction in productivity growth must be enduring: it occurs over the life-cycle of these divorcées. If it were only the case that income shocks occurred simultaneously with divorce events, the fact that divorce rates more than tripled over the 1960s and 1970s (Chart 2) would allow us to measure this fact. In effect, the loss of a job for a year or less would lead to the loss of something like a year’s income growth (Chart 4), but this income growth is variable by epoch. The effect of such a hypothetical immediate income shock is not seen at either 1970 or 1980---there is no change in the distance between the wage growth curves in Chart 4 even thought the ratio of “shocking” divorce events (Chart 2) to total divorcées (Chart 3) increases by nearly a factor of two for each of the foregoing decades (the 1960s and the 1970s): Simply compare the heights of the bars in Chart 2 to total divorcées---the red area in Chart 3.))
 +
 +{{ :chart_8.png?direct&550 |The Effect of Divorce on the United States: Redistribution of Populations into Lower Growth Classes}}
 +
 +{{ :chart_9.png?direct&550 |Determining the Effect of Divorce on the United States: Population Change & Differential Productivity}}
 +
 +=====3. Effects on the U.S. Economy=====
 +
 +The divorce revolution has [[effects_of_family_structure_on_poverty|undermined growth in the U.S. economy]].((This result follows from this analysis and the fact that there was no population effect (see [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/the-divorce-revolution-perpetually-reduces-u-s-economic-growth/]] for a full explanation; this is perhaps the most basic labor effect on economic production) from the ‘release’ of divorcées to the workforce across the 1970s and 1980s. This is easily demonstrated (this fact was earlier reported by Nobel Laureate Gary Becker in Gary Becker, //Treatise on the Family// (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1981), and we assert is strongly tied to the Solow growth paradox through [total] household productivity considerations). In [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/decline-of-economic-growth-human-capital-and-population-change/]] compare the (pure) population + human capital contributions to growth (Chart 1) to actual macro-economic growth (Chart 2). Women entered  the workforce predominantly in the 1970s and 1980s. Actual growth (Chart 1) began to slow during this period, even though the population effect of women entering the workforce alone should contribute more than 0.2% per year. Clearly this is not seen.
 +\\ In fact, the population + human capital contribution chart (Chart 1) in the (over-)simplicity of its model over-estimates growth by the factor this entry elucidates. The corrected model, which looks much more like the actual 1960s-1970s growth profile, has a flat-lining of economic growth in the 1970s, instead of a hump around 1970 which the naïve population-based model shows.)) Since marriage has a “remarkably large”((George Akerlof, “Men Without Children,” //The Economic Journal// 108 (Mar. 1998): 287-309.)) accruing effect on a worker’s productivity, divorce eliminates this agent for growth. Besides for population effects originating in the 1960s and 1970s, there are no other consequences of policy change that have had a greater effect in slowing economic growth than the divorce revolution. Divorce, having now become acculturated, perpetually [[effects_of_family_structure_on_government_dependency|inhibits growth of the U.S. economy]].((See Footnote 20. 
 +\\
 +\\
 +\\
 +This entry draws heavily from [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/decline-of-economic-growth-human-capital-and-population-change/|Decline of Economic Growth: Human Capital and Population Change]] and [[http://marri.us/research/research-papers/the-divorce-revolution-perpetually-reduces-u-s-economic-growth/|The Divorce Revolution Perpetually Reduces US Economic Growth]].))